The U.S. Supreme Court recently heard arguments on the legality of reverse payment settlements in the pharmaceutical sector, where a patent holder would pay a generic pharmaceutical manufacturer to delay or withdraw any challenges to patent validity. Given the increasing number of reverse payment settlements, the final holding of the U.S. Supreme Court is going to have a significant impact on competition in the pharmaceutical industry.
We have for our readers a guest post on this topic and the hearing before the Supreme Court, by Mr. George Yu, an experienced patent litigation lawyer at Schiff Hardin LLP. Mr. Yu’s practice focuses on patent infringement litigation and intellectual property counseling. Mr. Yu’s strong background in biochemistry and molecular biology enhance his experience in handling patent litigations involving complex pharmaceutical, biotechnology, and medical technology products. Prior to joining Schiff Hardin, Mr. Yu was Assistant General Counsel, Litigation for Affymetrix, Inc., the first company to commercialize DNA microarrays.
Federal Trade Commission v. Actavis, Inc: A Quick
Look into Reverse Payments
by
George Yu
The name of the game in the
pharmaceutical industry is exclusivity. According
to Drugs.com, sales in the US for a blockbuster drug like Lipitor® can go from
nearly $2 billion a quarter to less than $200M a quarter less than a year after
the introduction of a generic version of the drug. (See www.drugs.com.) On March 25, 2013, the U.S. Supreme Court
heard argument
in Fair Trade Commission v. Actavis (12-416)
regarding one of the strategies used by drug companies to extend their
exclusivity, the so-called “reverse payment settlement.”
The party wishing to practice a patent in
the typical patent licensing scenario provides a payment or other consideration
to the patentee in exchange for a promise by the patentee not to sue for
infringement. In the pharmaceutical
industry, the branded pharmaceutical company that owns a patent covering a drug
sometimes will pay a generic drug company that has filed an Abbreviated New
Drug Application under the Hatch-Waxman
Amendments to delay the entry of a competing product and withdraw
challenges to the validity of the patent.
These reverse payment or “pay-for-delay” settlements have become more
common in recent years and have been challenged by the Fair Trade Commission
(FTC), pharmaceutical wholesalers, and pharmacies as anticompetitive. The FTC estimated in
2010 that reverse payment settlements in the pharmaceutical industry cost U.S. consumers
$3.5 billion annually. The FTC published
another report
at the beginning of this year indicating an increase in reverse payment
settlements.
Actavis and the “scope of the patent” test
As discussed in the opinion of
the Eleventh Circuit Court of Appeals, the reverse payment settlement in Actavis relates to a patent set to
expire in 2020 covering a formulation of AndroGel®, a topical gel that treats
the symptoms of low testosterone in men.
Sales of AndroGel® generated revenue in excess of $1.8 billion between
2000 and 2007. Two drug companies filed
ANDAs to market generic versions of AndroGel®, leading to patent litigation
between the marketer of AndroGel® and the generic competitors. The generic drug companies estimated that the
generic version would sell at 25% of the price of AndroGel® and decrease sales
of AndroGel® by 90%.
In 2006, after the lifting of the
30-month stay when the litigation was still ongoing, the parties reached a
settlement under which the defendants agreed not market a generic version of
AndroGel® until August 31, 2015. During
the nine years of AndroGel® exclusivity, the generic drug companies would
receive a total of $29-40 million per year.
As required by statute, the parties reported their settlement to the
FTC.
The FTC then filed suit against the
settling parties alleging that the reverse payment settlements were unlawful agreements
not to compete. The FTC asserted that
the patentee was not likely to prevail in the infringement actions because of
the persuasive arguments regarding the invalidity and noninfringement of the
asserted patent. The FTC argued that
because the AndroGel® patent “was unlikely to prevent generic entry,” the
reverse payments extended an unauthorized monopoly.
The district court dismissed the FTC’s
complaint based on Eleventh Circuit precedent because the FTC did not allege
that the settlement imposed a greater exclusion than that provided by the patent
itself. The FTC appealed, challenging
the “scope of the patent” test for anticompetitive behavior. The Eleventh Circuit affirmed, and the FTC petitioned
the Supreme Court for review. The
briefs, including a number of amicus
curiae briefs, can be found here,
including a brief
from one of the co-sponsors of the Hatch-Waxman amendments, Rep. Henry Waxman.
K-Dur and the “quick look” test
Shortly after the Eleventh Circuit’s
decision in Actavis, the Third
Circuit considered a similar appeal and reached a different result based on a
different legal test. The In re K-Dur Antitrust Litigation appeal related to
the settlement of patent litigations involving patents covering a
controlled-release microencapsulated potassium chloride formulation. One settlement required the generic drug
company to delay entry of its product of four years for a payment of $60
million. But the settlement also
included a cross-license to certain patents owned by the generic drug company.
Despite the branded and generic drug
companies’ argument that the payment related to the licensing of patents not
involved in the litigation, the Third Circuit found that there was a reverse
payment. After reviewing the precedent
from other circuits, the K-Dur panel
rejected the scope of the patent test because reverse payments “permit the
sharing of monopoly rents between would-be competitors without any assurance
that the underlying patent is valid.” Instead,
the Third Circuit held that courts should apply a “quick look rule of reason”
analysis, which shifts the burden to defendants to provide evidence that per se illegal behavior had an economic
justification. Under those
circumstances, defendants in quick look situations have only rarely been able
to provide the justification necessary to avoid antitrust liability.
The K-Dur
defendants also petitioned for review by the Supreme Court, which has yet
to rule on their petition.
The Oral Argument in actavis
Deputy Solicitor General, Malcolm
Stewart, argued
on behalf of the Government, while Jeffrey Weinberger argued on behalf of the
respondent pharmaceutical companies.
Justice Samuel Alito recused himself from the proceedings. Thus, a 4-4 decision, which would uphold the
Eleventh Circuit’s ruling that the settlements are lawful, is possible.
Shortly after Mr. Stewart began his
argument in support of the quick look test, Justice Scalia challenged him to
identify “a case in which the patentee acting within the scope of the patent
has nonetheless been held liable under the antitrust laws.” Justice Kennedy indicated his concern that
the quick look test makes no attempt to distinguish between weak patents and
strong patents because settlements involving either would be presumptively
unlawful. Justice Breyer, on the other
hand, asked why the Government would not be satisfied with an acknowledgement
that reverse payment settlements sometimes have anticompetitive effects and
should be subject to the standard rule of reason analysis without a presumption
for or against legality. Mr. Stewart
responded that such an approach would bring in the “kitchen sink”—i.e., unnecessarily complicate the
analysis.
For respondents, Mr. Weinberger responded
to the question posed by Justice Scalia by stating that there had in fact been
no decision where the court “has ever found a restraint outside the scope of
the patent to be unlawful.” However, Justice
Sotomayor challenged Mr. Weinberger to suggest another licensing situation
where a patentee and a licensee appear to be sharing the monopoly profits. Failing to provide a clear example in
response to Justice Sotomayor, Mr. Weinberger argued instead that judges would
have a hard time determining whether a given agreement was anticompetitive
under the rule of reason.
The questions posed at the argument
suggest that Justice Scalia favors affirmance, while four justices (Kennedy,
Breyer, Sotomayor, and Kagan) favor applying the rule of reason analysis or
require at least some additional analysis of the anticompetitive effects beyond
either the “scope of the patent” and “quick look” tests. A decision is expected in the early summer.
This post represents solely the views of
the author and does not represent the views of Schiff Hardin LLP or any clients
of Schiff Hardin LLP.
No comments:
Post a Comment